Parliamentary democracy in Papua New Guinea

Bill Geddes (2010)

 

Papua New Guinea comprises the eastern half of the largest island in the Pacific region and more than 600 offshore islands, including New Britain, New Ireland and Bougainville, with a total land area of a little over 450 000 sq. km and a coastline of more than 5000 km. The main island consists of a high mountain chain broken into ranges divided by wide valleys running east to west, with extensive foothills and swamps to the north and the south. It shares a land border of 820 km with Irian Jaya, a province of Indonesia, and sea borders with Australia to the south and the Solomon Islands to the east. It has a tropical monsoon climate, with annual rainfall averages from 119 cm at Port Moresby, to 508 cm in the mountainous Western areas.

Its population in 2007 was estimated at 6.3 million people, with an average annual growth rate of 2.2 per cent; lower than Nigeria's, but still high. The capital, Port Moresby, has an estimated population of about 254 000, the next largest town being Lae with a population of about 78 000. Other urban centres are considerably smaller and less than 15 per cent of the population live in urban areas.

The Summer Institute of Linguistics lists 867 separate languages and dialects for the population, giving an average speaking population for each language of less than 4300 people. However, numbers of speakers range from 100-200 people to more than 10 000 for some of the larger language groups. Pidgin has emerged over the past century as the lingua franca of the region and forms one of the official languages (with English) of the nation.

Prior to independence, Papua New Guinea was governed by Australia as a United Nations Trust Territory. Until after the Second World War, peoples of the interior of the main island had very little direct contact with the Western world. The highlands of Papua New Guinea were only entered by Europeans during the 1930s and no substantial administrative presence developed until the mid-1950s. So, most Highlanders had been involved in Western forms of administration for less than thirty years when Papua New Guinea gained independence in 1975. It is, therefore, unremarkable that national and regional politics in the country take their flavour from indigenous forms of leadership.

As in any Third World country, political activity and performance can only be understood in terms of indigenous political understandings and practices. As Tony Barnett has described:

Political leadership in the local community in PNG, and particularly in the highlands, has always had its origins in complex sets of ceremonial reciprocal exchanges. Status in the local community is achieved through processes of political manipulation. Through these manipulations a man becomes a big man. Successful big men become village councillors. Of these, the more influential gain access to the next level of local government, the area authority. Some area authorities have become, or are in the process of becoming, provincial governments ... the more effective big men from the area authorities are the main contenders for, and occupants of, seats in the [national] House of Assembly. Their election to the house and continuing presence therein depends on their ability adequately to meet the obligations in ritual exchange upon which their status and thus political support is dependent.

(Barnett 1979, pp. 769-70)

To prepare the country for independence, a Constitutional Planning Committee was appointed by the Papua New Guinea House of Assembly in 1972. In investigating possible alternative structures for the future government of the nation, it spelt out its view of what had happened to Papua New Guinea communities during the colonial period:

When Europeans first settled in PNG, they did not find a political vacuum on the shore and plains, or in the mountains and valleys of our islands. Our ancestors lived and worked in communities­ - villages, hamlets, clans and tribes-with their own forms of social organisation, appropriate to their needs. However, colonial rule has an important impact upon the character and lifestyles of our people. It placed new requirements upon them. It ignored, or opposed, or sought to alter, our traditional forms of social organisation without proper consultation with our people. It deprived us of self-­government, and even of self-respect. The proud independence of our local communities was replaced by dependence-upon the all­-powerful representative of the colonial government-the Kiap [District Officer].

(CPC Report 1975, cited by Premdas & Steeves 1984, p. 34)

District officers, in most colonial countries, were given authority over administrative districts. They were the face of the colonial power for most of the indigenous population. As the above report says, the district officer, or Kiap, was 'the all-powerful representative of the colonial government'. On the political and directive level, communities were subjected to district officer's authority and to the authority of those deputised to carry out the requirements of the administration.

This form of autocratic, bureaucratic government could not, of course, continue in an independent country. Australia, inevitably, saw its own system of government as the most effective it could offer the new nation and set about devising a Westminster-style parliament, bureaucracy and electoral system. Fundamental to the new system was the idea of participatory democracy. Whereas the colonial administration had been a directive, non-consultative one, those who exercised power in the new nation could be held accountable to the electorate for their actions, and for the actions of the bureaucracy they had inherited. The new government would have to address two major issues: 'the establishment of political control over the bureaucracy and the breaking down of the highly centralised pattern of exercising control' it inherited (PPC 1990, p. 6). Both would be strongly resisted, since the bureaucracy, though 'localised' initially, still functioned as it had in the pre-independence period.

The new government also inherited a population divided into more than 800 distinct groups which had no history of unified activity, or of thinking in terms of the possibility of 'national interest'. The dilemma for national politicians required to take responsibility for the nation as a whole was that having been elected by local communities, and relying on those communities for re-election, Australian advisers insisted that as national parliamentarians they were required to make decisions 'in the national interest', rather than in the interests of their supporters.

In September 1975, at the time of independence, Bougainville, a province of Papua New Guinea, seceded, but returned to the fold several months later after negotiating preferential terms for itself, and, by extension, for other provincial governments. A number of provinces have used the threat of secession over the past twenty-five years in the attempt to gain improved conditions and terms from the national government, although only on Bougainville has that degenerated into open war between secessionists and the national defence force. Although the terms negotiated extended the powers of provincial governments beyond those initially envisaged in pre-independence planning, the decentralisation of government from the centre to the periphery was in line with that planning.

In the 1970s, when Papua New Guinea was being groomed for independence, conventional wisdom in development circles held that in order to ensure grassroots involvement in political and economic development, it was necessary to involve people as directly as possible in the responsibilities of government. Premdas and Steeves spelt out the rationale clearly:

If decolonisation means anything, it would at least entail the dismantling and re-orienting of the inherited bureaucracy rendering government administrative behaviour subservient to community will ... The overdeveloped centre must be deconcentrated to the periphery; a meaningful measure of autonomy in political decision making should be devolved to the vast majority of citizens who are rural dwellers (Nyerere 1968; Maddick 1968).

(Premdas & Steeves 1984, p. 2)

Those responsible for Papua New Guinea's moves to independence took the advice of Australian development personnel seriously. As Andrew Axline describes:

At the time of independence in 1975 Papua New Guinea embarked on a series of policies which, among other things, aimed to overcome two of the legacies of the colonial experience: the high degree of centralisation of political and administrative power, and the great geographical inequality of wealth and distribution of government services within the country '" Papua New Guinea embarked on a process of decentralisation at a time when thinking about development put an emphasis on self-reliance, more equitable distribution of wealth, and greater political participation. It is not surprising, then, that these aims are reflected in the existing decentralised system of government in Papua New Guinea ...

(Axline 1988, pp. 72-3)

A key element in the decentralisation program was the establishment of provincial governments with responsibility for a variety of government services including health, education, primary industry, commerce and bureau of management services. According to the legislation, the national government was obliged to provide 'unconditional' grants for the maintenance of the transferred services. These grants were based on the actual 1977 expenditures for those services, the year before the first of the provinces, New Britain and New Ireland, were given full financial responsibility for their own operations. Provinces were also guaranteed the net proceeds of a number of national taxes within their regions-such as registration and licensing fees-and were given power to impose a range of taxes of their own.

As Keith Hinchliffe has argued:

... one of the prices which has had to be paid to preserve national unity by both the public service and the state has been a very substantial amount of administrative and financial decentralisation ... Demands for decentralisation came from the provinces ... It was perhaps inevitable that the new political leaders of Papua New Guinea would be strongly influenced by the new doctrines of development theory and policy which were emerging in academic, and in some aid agency circles. These doctrines stressed the benefits of self-reliance, greater interpersonal and inter-regional equality, plus administrative decentralisation.

(Hinchliffe 1980, pp. 820, 830 & 837)

So, as a result of pressures from provincial regions and development advisers, and an attempt to particularise service provision at the regional level (thus making the provision of services more directly the concern of people within their own districts), Papua New Guinea devolved governmental responsibility to a second tier of politicians and bureaucrats.

Within five years of moving to establish provincial governments, questions were being raised as to their viability and usefulness. As William Tordoff describes, in 1984 the Prime Minister, Michael Somare:

... announced that a referendum would be held in order to determine whether or not provincial government should be retained ... A number of considerations probably led So mare to take this initiative. First, the Auditor-General's (delayed) reports on the public accounts of provinces for the fiscal year ended 31 December 1982 revealed serious financial mismanagement in several provinces, causing a number of provincial governments to be suspended. Secondly, the weakness of financial accountability and budget control in many provinces increased back-bench and even ministerial pressure for change ... Warren Dutton (North Fly), a former minister, stated: 'The evidence everywhere is that provincial government is closer to the people in towns and far, far further away from the people in the villages than the national Government district administration ever was.'

(Tordoff 1987, pp. 51-2)

Nothing came of the move and provincial government remained in Papua New Guinea until 1995. During that period, however, a number of provincial governments were sacked for maladministration and corruption and there was growing dissatisfaction at the national level with the performances of regional politicians and bureaucrats. Provincial politicians were accused of siphoning large amounts of money out of government coffers as competition developed between politicians for the allegiances of voters-though provincial politicians accused national politicians of being responsible for this misappropriation of government funds-and of mismanaging their responsibilities. As Sir Barry Holloway, a former national parliamentarian, wrote in the Papua New Guinea Times:

Some provincial governments have been suspended, others are bad and some may look good and I would be the last to make judgement on a premier or his assembly. They are, however, part of a system which is a total disaster for this country. In the same breath I would say that regional government would even be a greater disaster. It is a system of government that neither decentralises or supports the central system. In most parts of the country it is the root cause of the deterioration of services to the people and an inhibiting factor in the quest for economic development. It is totally destructive to the true philosophy of decentralisation and a grass roots system of government ... Provincial governments in most cases represent nothing but an arbitrary collection of the numerous ethnic groups of this nation without any tie as to how they should relate one to the other ... No longer does the local government council have a pride in its affairs, the capacity to upgrade schools and clinics or even to maintain the potholes in the secondary and tertiary roads. Basic community medicine programmes in relation to hygiene, nutrition, infant welfare and malaria control do not even exist in the villages any longer. Small ethnic groups in well settled peaceful provinces are fragmenting into warlord kingdoms as a result of there being no longer any contact or involvement with any government.

(Holloway 1990, p. 22)

National dissatisfaction with the performance of regional politicians had its roots both in the objective performance of provincial governments and also in the direct rivalry which developed between provincial and national politicians. (This same competition between parliamentarians for recognition as leaders amongst their constituents was a very real problem in Nigeria's brief experiments with democracy.) As the Permanent Parliamentary Committee on Provincial Government Suspension (PPC) suggested in 1990, the most:

... obvious manifestation of the new pattern of political relationships is to be found in the interaction between national and provincial political leaders. With the creation of nineteen political systems at the provincial level, opportunity for the emergence of a whole new set of political leaders was also created. These new leaders-provincial assembly members, provincial ministers, and provincial premiers ­are elected by and represent the same constituents as do national Members of Parliament. While the two sets of leaders do not compete for the same elected office, they are very much in competition for recognition as leaders of the same people.

(PPC 1990, p. 15)

This, inevitably, set national and provincial parliamentarians against each other, with each arguing for ascendancy. As the report says:

This underlying political rivalry has contributed to a national­provincial polarisation in Papua New Guinea, resulting in strong anti­provincial government sentiments in Parliament and among national ministers.

(PPC 1990, p. 15)

According to the report, one manifestation of this rivalry has been persistent attempts by national politicians to divert public money to their supporters. 'The capture by politicians of the NPEP Sectoral Funds in Transport and Agriculture which were designed to offset the disadvantage of less well-endowed provinces in obtaining development funds is the most notorious of these' (PPC 1990, p. 16). According to the Commission, provincial governments have also been undermined in a number of other ways through decisions made in Port Moresby, aimed at the breakdown of effective administration at a provincial level.

This rivalry culminated, in 1995, with a bill being passed through the national parliament disbanding provincial government and returning all their powers to Port Moresby. 'The legislation swept through with a crushing 86-15 vote after [Prime Minister] Chan smoothed Opposition protests by promising amendments after the Bill's passage'. As David Robie, writing for Gemini News Service described:

Papua New Guinea has thrown out its provincial government system in spite of bitter opposition from several premiers. The Prime Minister has hailed the new law as the 'most crucial achievement since independence'. However ... some opponents claim the country is sliding into dictatorship ... Eighteen out of 19 provincial governments will be tossed out. Only the National Capital District and peace transition administration in Bougainville province will survive: the latter has a deadline for a new political arrangement by the next general election in 1997. Financial power in Papua New Guinea will now become centralised and provincial development programs will need backing from the national government in Port Moresby ... A senior politician losing his job under the reforms, West New Britain Premier Bernard Vogae, claimed the country was sliding towards dictatorship: 'This is an example of a dictatorship and the beginning of the disappearance of a democracy that the people have enjoyed over the past 20 years ... The people of PNG have the right to know what the reforms are all about and how they are going to be affected,' Vogae added. Maino warned the reform concentrated too much power on MP's. 'The reform Bill is designed to give our MPs more powers and more control which could lead to more abuses, more misappropriation of public funds and more corruption,' he said. Prime Minister Chan described the legislation as the most crucial achievement since independence. He praised the 'guts and courage' of MPs who voted for the bipartisan legislation. 'This is probably the greatest moment of my political career-it wasn't a government or political victory of any particular party,' he said. 'We had a system of provincial government that has failed our people, and it is fitting that as we approach our 20th anniversary of independence, we make a change for a brighter, better future.'

(Robie 1995)

Rather than making government more effective, decentralisation provided another tier of parliamentarians whose primary allegiances were to their constituents rather than to the provincial government, and who saw government as a resource to be tapped rather than as an efficient and effective provider of services. And, since local rivalries were played out in relations between provincial and national parliamentarians, decentralisation simply provided an elaborated set of big man rivalries, with all the requirements of redistribution and favour through which Papua New Guinea leaders cement their positions among their supporters.

While decentralisation proved less than workable, attempts to ensure that national parliamentarians were insulated from the corrosive effects of local, constituent demands were little more successful. In an attempt to provide national parliamentarians with resources to satisfy the demands of constituents, in 1984, Michael Somare provided funds which could be used by members of parliament within their own electorates. Rather than each parliamentarian trying to carve out funds for his or her1 own region from the general governmental coffers, people could focus on how their politician disbursed the funds allocated to him or her for this purpose. This still produced weak government, since those elected were only weakly-or not at all-committed to particular 'parties' and coalitions of parliamentarians were unstable and easily disrupted, but it was an attempt to resolve the problem of members being judged by their ability to bring amounts of money and goods to their communities.

As might have been predicted, in the ensuing years a great deal of parliamentary debate and activity went into attempting to expand the amount of money made available to parliamentarians for disbursement in the electorates. By 1995, the amount obtained by each member of parliament for this disbursement had increased from an initial 30 000 kina2 to 500 000 kina a year. Yet, this strategy had not made members of parliament any more secure. As many as sixty per cent of parliamentarians lost their seats in each election during the 1990s. This huge turnover seems largely to have been due to two factors. First, since members of electorates considered election to parliamentary office a sinecure, it was widely felt that no-one had the right to permanent election. When a member had served one or two terms, a likely argument in electing someone else was that it was time another person, and therefore another group, was given access to the resource. Second, unless the amounts being siphoned from government to electorates constantly increased, there was a perception that the member was not doing the job for which he or she had been elected.

Politics and indigenous leadership

At the national level in Papua New Guinea, politics was based on opportunism, on seeking alliances which would best secure access to the funds necessary to ensure political survival, or on preventing others from entering such alliances. As Griffith and King (1985) say:

If big man democracy and political opportunism were MA's [Melanesian Alliance] bugbear, opportunism almost constituted the ruling philosophy of the United Party. In a disarmingly frank presentation at the University of Papua New Guinea, Roy Evara elevated political flexibility into a principle: 'During my time in office as leader of the United Party, when there were changes of government, the United Party was always there. We never missed ... It was the United Party who brought the change of government [in March 1980] ... We were able to cross the floor to join this party and that party. Other people have said these people are like pamuk meri [prostitutes], they go here, they go there. Yes, we did that ... Having achieved these changes in government we also undertook the task of breaking every other party ... We wanted to make Julius [Chan] weak, and then we wanted to make Somare weak. So in this election we will all be saying, no party is going to be strong enough to form a one-party government'.

(Griffin & King 1985, pp. 63-4, in King 1989, p. 15)

This form of activity not only reflects the opportunism of parliamentarians intent on gaining as much as possible for themselves and their own electorates and, at the same time, intent on minimising the returns to other parliamentarians and their constituents. It also reflects the particular focuses of big man activity within many Papua New Guinean communities.3 Big man activity is as focused on undermining one's opposition as it is on building up one's own status. In fact, given the rapidly mounting costs of increased recognition and status, it is often far more effective to be recognised as adept at undermining those with whom one competes than it is to attempt to promote oneself. In the face of these pressures, political leaders were compelled to satisfy the demands of parliamentarians like Roy Evara in order to maintain power. And the chief demands of parliamentarians related to funding 'development' activities in their home regions in ways which would clearly demonstrate to their constituents that they had personally delivered the expenditures involved.

Papua New Guinea, in common with many Third World nations, has a splintered past. As Peter Loveday has described:

PNG was not one country, institutionally or in any other way when its history as a colony began. It was and still is a collection of societies and a stateless collection at that ... It has no sense of a past as a society, let alone as a polity, and no residue or memory of traditional national institutions that it can revive and adapt to the needs of a modernising country. The present chief minister, Michael Somare, summed up the consequence not long ago: the country, he said, had a problem of identity-'we have no feeling of national consciousness, no unification, tribes are fragmented, there are no large tribes ... no chieftains or ruling societies and no common language' (Somare 1970:490-1 'Problems of political organisation in diversified tribes in Papua New Guinea' in Ward 1970:489-493). Traditional politics had no national component and still is largely the politics of establishing and maintaining a functionally undifferentiated and normally non­hereditary leadership, limited in geographical scope and social range and unable to call on authority or the force behind it to sanction its decisions and recommendations ( ... Salisbury 1970:313,328-31). As a form of politics it is intensely individualistic and yet also intensely communalistic.

(Loveday 1975, p. 2)

In order to understand the nature of leadership in Papua New Guinean communities and the ways in which the exercise of that leadership affects parliamentary performance, we need to understand the nature of big man leadership. It is a contention of this discussion that parliamentary leadership in any Third World country betrays the characteristics of the dominant forms and requirements of leadership in that country's communities. In Papua New Guinea, despite a wide variation in the particulars of leadership forms and requirements, leadership is competitive, yet consensual. An understanding of big man leadership will provide us with an understanding of the forms and styles of leadership found in Papua New Guinea politics at the provincial and national levels. We need, therefore, to briefly examine the nature and forms of big man leadership in Papua New Guinea communities.

The relationship between leaders and the communities they lead can be understood on a continuum 4. At the left pole of the continuum is consensual leadership, and at the right pole is coercive leadership. The mid-point on the continuum is charismatic, consultative leadership. Papua New Guinea community leadership is consensual. The leader who leads by consensus is one who is approved by the community and is subject to constant community scrutiny of his or her performance. When the performance fails to satisfy community members, a variety of disciplinary processes are enacted through which the leader is either corrected or displaced. In the Papua New Guinea context, as Podolefsky suggests:

... the authority of the traditional big man was embedded in his network of social relations ... Big men had influence but there was no formal authority vested in the position ... Big men take the lead in a variety of settings, including speaking during disputes. However, 'No leader can be sure that his opinion will be respected, that his orders will be obeyed, that he will be helped in avenging his wrongs, that his suggestion to hold a ceremony will be taken up, or that the points he makes in a bragging speech to another tribe will be supported by his fellow-tribesmen' (Brown 1963:6).

(Podolefsky 1990, pp. 67-8)

In societies where leadership is consensual, leaders can never be sure that those they represent will back them unless they have first obtained their approval and support for an undertaking. This requires constant interaction with the community, constant reaffirmation of support. To act alone is to run the risk of being accused of arrogance, of ignoring public opinion. Of course, such leadership is tenuous and communities which allow their leaders as little leeway as this will find it difficult to co-ordinate group activities or interact readily with other communities. Big men had and have a variety of means for increasing their authority and therefore their ability to lead.

Wayne Warry spells out some of the general features of big men for Chuave leadership among the Simbu:

Three generalisations, still applicable today, seem justified. First, bigmen could be associated with particular men's houses and still act as leaders of subclans and lineages. Secondly, where men of equal power existed they reached tacit or implicit agreements concerning their respective domains. Thus, rivals resided in different men's houses and, in exchanges, dominated only those distributions involving their own social groups. Thirdly, young men first achieved recognition within their own lineage and men's house group and only later became authorised leaders of subclans or extended their authority to other men's houses ... the defining characteristics of a bigman were and are oratorical skill, expertise as a distributor or manager of group valuables, and an ability to mediate in disputes ... In order to distribute valuables and challenge the authority of an existing leader, a young man must contribute a large amount of his own personal wealth in given exchanges or sponsor his own ceremonies ... Once a bigman has demonstrated his ability to provide a fair distribution of valuables and to act as group spokesman, however, he needs only to expend a minimum of his wealth and may even act in this capacity when he has not contributed to particular exchanges. In the past young men also built reputations as fierce warriors, but an established bigman's life, some say, was too important to be risked and a bigman rarely, if ever, participated in battle ...

(Warry 1987, p. 56)

So, while big men were, and are, directly answerable to the community which supports them, there are strategies through which they can enhance their prestige and gain increased support from the community. In effect, a successful big man builds a reputation for generosity, fairness and for 'looking after' those who depend on him. He can then, in specific situations, trade on that reputation, and so act with a fair degree of certainty of community support. There are, of course, other ways in which a big man might bolster his authority. Warry says:

In Chuave a generalised ideology of hereditary leadership and a specific method of succession within the lineage endowed certain individuals with advantages most of their peers did not have and so enabled a few men an easier pathway to power ... Achieved criteria are the basis for initial recruitment, but when ambitious men emerge appeals to hereditary rules further bolster their status and power, and disadvantage their competitors. Furthermore, where no hereditary advantage exists, or conversely where people regard the advantaged few as inadequate leaders, men adjust beliefs about ascribed status to accommodate or rationalise post facto the status of the emergent bigman. This contradiction is real: in Chuave an ideology of hereditary leadership exists, but the nature of succession is such that achieved and not ascribed traits predominate in the selection of leaders.

(Warry 1987, p. 57)

So, once recognised as a big man, an individual can appeal to hereditary ties to further bolster his position. He can show that he is related to other successful and important leaders from the past and thus hope that some of the prestige and status of those leaders will accrue to himself. In fact, in a number of Papua New Guinean societies, the hereditary basis for leadership is more strongly established and leaders gain some prestige and authority from their clan and family connections. As Karen Brison has claimed:

Melanesian societies are often described as 'egalitarian' Coo. Sahlins 1963), but Kwanga society also is not entirely lacking in concepts of rightful hierarchy or in legitimate means of coercion. In fact, it could be argued that Kwanga communities are permeated by a sense of rightful hierarchy. The genealogically senior men of lineages have authority over their juniors, allocate group resources, make decisions on communal exchange obligations, speak for their lineages in public gatherings, and control hunting and gardening magic. Furthermore, Kwanga men are initiated into a multigraded cult in which they are taught hunting, gardening, and war magic necessary to the well-being of the community. The cult also creates hierarchy within the group of initiated men since initiates of higher grades have authority over their cult juniors. Initiated men not only have authority but are also believed to have coercive powers to punish violations of social norms and cult rules, in the form of sorcerers who act at their bidding. In short, Kwanga society has both legitimate hierarchy and (at least in local belief) leaders with power since, whether or not magic is practiced or effective, as long as people believe that it is, this amounts to coercive sanction.

(Brison 1992, pp. 29-30)

Papua New Guinean societies have often been described as 'egalitarian'.

That is, there is an assumption of 'equality' amongst community members, and individuals act in a non-egalitarian manner at their own peril. However, as Karen Brison describes, and as others have noted, most communities are inherently hierarchical, not egalitarian (Geddes, Hughes & Remenyi 1994, p. 107; Jolly 1987). Although individuals who attempt to accrue power to themselves do so at their own peril, various roles in the community are imbued with authority, and those who aspire to those positions, obtain, with the role, the authority inherent in it (Geddes, Hughes & Remenyi 1994, pp. 104-8). To the extent that individuals carry out the responsibilities of their positions, they gain respect and recognition in the community. To the extent that they attempt to use their acquired position as a basis for personal power, to further their own ambitions, they attract suspicion and opposition from other members of the community. In big man societies, individuals achieve increased status and changed role definition through behaving in ways appropriate to a person with the position to which they aspire. To do this, they need to convince community members that they conform more closely to the defined characteristics of big men than those who are already identified with such roles in the community. That is, they don't demand new status definition, but act in ways which demonstrate that they have all the characteristics and virtues of one with such status.

Since young men are brought up to want to aspire to increased status, to being recognised as big men, many young men try to act in ways appropriate for big men. The trick is to act as a big man without appearing to be promoting oneself at the expense of anyone else. So, the lower one's present status, the more clearly and completely one needs to comply with the community's perceptions of ideal leadership behaviour. As Paula Brown has shown (1990, p. 98), most communities are very aware of the behaviours expected of big men and those who aspire to being recognised as such must conform to those community understandings. Among the attributes of a big man identified by Sahlins (1963) are 'oratory and the capacity to attract followers to political programs and group activities'. Oliver (1955) says that the leader is qualified by ambition, generosity, skill and industriousness; Chowning and Goodenough (1971) claim that they are managers distinguished by seniority, industry, wealth, responsibility, courage, knowledge, and ambition; and Read (1959) claims that they are assertive, aggressive, influential, gift-giving directors whose success in warfare was tempered by the values of equivalence and consensus.

Obviously, there is a fine line to be drawn between the kinds of behaviour expected by the community and behaviours which will draw accusations of self-interest and self-promotion. As Karen Brison has observed:

Something seems to be constraining assertive leadership, but what is it? I will examine the dense network of social relationships in a small village society and argue that these create a situation in which almost anything anybody does provokes a negative reaction. Consequently, people seek ways to influence events without incurring the personal costs of taking responsibility for leadership. Spreading malicious rumours is one such strategy; making speeches in meetings is another.

(Brison 1992, p. 31)

To be assertive, unless one has already achieved a position which legitimises this, leads inevitably to opposition from community members. In any society, those who clearly act in ways inappropriate to their current status attract criticism and opposition. So, one must find ways of influencing events, of acting as an emergent big man without attracting negative consequences. Also, since any attempt at attaining big man status inevitably affects the status of other aspirants as well as of those who are already recognised as big men, others will be on the lookout for possible challengers and will attempt to undermine their reputations. Brison explains this well:

People like to drop hints and to spread malicious rumours in small communities because it is a way of influencing events without facing the consequences; but everyone realises that since individuals prefer such covert strategies, nothing anyone says or does can be taken at face value. Indeed, I will suggest that small communities like Kwanga villages are characterised by a pervasive spirit of distrust in which everyone looks for nefarious hidden plots behind apparently innocuous surfaces. This spirit of distrust, in turn, both creates rumours as people speculate about what lies hidden from view and makes villagers particularly prone to believing inflammatory gossip-because they are predisposed to think that their neighbours are up to no good. In short, suspicion and distrust create a preference for gossiping which increases suspicion and distrust and so on.

The result is an environment where it is difficult for anyone to attain or consolidate power. Almost anything leaders do creates resentment and rumours; some try to influence events in covert ways to escape the criticism and backbiting; but such strategies increase the people's distrust of leaders and can blacken the reputations of particular leaders to the point where they may be attacked or ostracised. Thus, ironically, the same leaders who hint and gossip to attain 'power without responsibility' ultimately become the victims of rumours themselves. Talk, then, does more than reflect egalitarian social conditions created by political ideology or the economy; patterns of talk in many ways create and maintain the egalitarian ethos by making it difficult for anyone to consolidate power.

(Brison 1992, pp. 31-2)

As Podolefsky (1990) suggests, the control exercised within small communities, such as those within which big men operate, is implicit rather than explicit. That is, there is not an objective, spelt-out set of rules governing behaviour and interaction which is applied by recognised authorities. Rather, people in the community, when they find a particular person difficult to deal with, will mobilise public opinion by gossiping about them. If others also have a problem, or if the person initiating it is good at it, the gossip becomes rumour and is spread throughout the community, gathering momentum as it goes.

The nature of rumour makes it extremely difficult to pinpoint its origin, and so those who find themselves the butt of gossip and innuendo must find ways of countering it. In Kwanga communities, as in many other small communities, people take advantage of public meetings to clear their names. In the process, if they are not careful, the very act of addressing a rumour might give it added substance, and so discussion becomes oblique and referential, with people alluding to issues which are often not spelt-out and which require a knowledge of the circulating rumours. This, in turn, makes it important that people know the rumours that are circulating and adds further impetus to community gossip. In order to protect their names and to stifle gossip, people must constantly interact with others and project themselves in ways which will call into question any negative gossip. So, people work at conforming, at behaving as they know others expect them to. It is dangerous to stand out and act as an independent individual.

Parliamentarians who decide to act in the national, rather than in the local and regional interest, risk far more than the loss of their seats. They risk their reputations, their acceptance as leaders at the regional and local levels and social ostracism. They must ensure that they have relatives and friends in their regions who will actively promote their interests, who will defend them against rumour and gossip. And in order to ensure this, they must show that they have the best interests of those people in mind in their activities while in the capital.

So parliamentarians find themselves having to constantly remember that their actions and attitudes are being scrutinised, that stories are being passed back to their communities and that people at home are gossiping. To counteract gossip, which is far more often scandalous than laudatory, they must very evidently behave in ways which undermine circulating stories. Whether in the capital or at home, parliamentarians must behave as big men behave towards their own communities. So, being elected to the national parliament does not free a person from the pressures and responsibilities that go with status in Papua New Guinean communities; it accentuates them. The result is a national parliament in which most politicians are more concerned with self-preservation and with promoting their reputations in their home communities and regions than in 'national' government. As Andrew Strathern has described:

By the 1980s it was understood that politicians are in power to benefit themselves and their factions, and they concentrate on consolidating their existing power bases. As a result of armed conflicts between groups these bases had become more, rather than less, rigidly defined and a process of neotribalism was well under way ... One long term friend of mine, who told me that of course now it was absolutely necessary for rival candidates to outbid each other in offers of bribes to every individual elector, added that the people were sure (from what the candidates themselves had said) that this was 'the way of the white man' and had just reached Papua New Guinea. When I protested this view, he appeared shocked and begged me not to spread the point around, for fear that I might be physically attacked and silenced by politicians and their followers alike.

(Strathern 1993, p. 48)

The rivalries that develop, both within and between electoral regions, result in escalating tension, as Strathern describes:

Politicians ... by fostering local factions in pursuit of personal power, may actually stir up conflicts and increase their significance beyond the local level ... the situation has been made much more precarious since the introduction of firearms into fighting and criminal actions in the Highlands (and elsewhere). The ambiguous role of politicians in this situation is made clear by the recurrent suspicion on the part of ordinary people (and some electoral officials also) that certain politicians are amongst the most important suppliers of guns to their constituents, largely because guns buy votes.

(Strathern 1993, pp. 46-7)

Not only do communities oppose one another, they view all opposed forces and groups as communities with whom they are competitively opposed and act against them on that basis. So, attempts by provincial and national governmental groups to superimpose their wishes and ideas on local communities trigger similar reactions from the communities to those which are triggered by the activities of rival communities. As Strathern says:

Clans seem to treat the state, national and provincial authorities as another clan and to direct their demands against all entities in the outside world in the exact way they do against their immediate neighbours. They appear to know that violent actions can be effective in changing governmental attitudes towards them, whereas peaceful methods tend to be futile. From their perspective, then, their behaviour is highly rational, while at the same time it is deeply damaging to the fabric of state legitimacy.

(Strathern 1993, p. 54)

As the state becomes embroiled in the tensions and antagonisms of regional politics, it increasingly loses legitimacy as an integrating, superior authority, and becomes recognised as just another player, opposing the self­interested activities of particular communities and regions with its own self-interested alternatives.

The politician, as a member of the national or provincial government, faces the problem of increasing violence and the subversion of national priorities to regional interests and is required to address these issues in legislation. At one level, the parliamentarian finds himself a member of a community of politicians and bureaucrats, and, instinctively, acts within that community to obtain big man status in relation to other community members. Since all those who belong to this community are already successful to one degree or another within their constituent communities, the competition at the national level becomes far stronger than that at the local level. And parliamentarians are constantly forming and breaking alliances as they prove useful or counter-productive, and participating in rumour-mongering or defending themselves against gossip and innuendo. The political games in provincial and national centres echo those at the local level, and parliamentarians find themselves preoccupied with the problems of maintaining big man status in the various communities within which they are placed.

As parliamentarians operating within that community, they accept the responsibility of setting legislation in place which will provide government agencies with authority in dealing with escalating tension and corruption. They also actively oppose such corruption since it is against their own interests for others to successfully siphon resources from national coffers. Yet, at another level, those who are responsible for enacting legislation must deliver results to their home communities, since otherwise they will lose status and support.

They are, therefore, directly involved in activities which lead both to legislation opposing violence and corruption and to the violence and corruption which they have opposed and which plague the country. As Strathern says:

... the roots of this decline date to at least the time of independence, when many Highlanders were opposed to the departure of the Australian Administration. The indigenous politicians had therefore a hard job to replace their colonial mentors in the first place. But their attempts to set up patronage networks of their own, mingled with their almost-inevitable embroilment in intergroup conflicts, have now created a situation in which they on the one hand make laws to control violence and crime and on the other are implicated in processes that escalate the overall level of violence in their areas ... Politicians are admired and accepted by the people as personal leaders in the style of leaders of small-scale polities in the past. They are not judged in terms of their adherence to laws but purely in terms of what they do for their people, however they manage this. In a sense, their legitimacy in the people's eyes depends solely on this aspect of their role. But actions that are legitimate in this sense may in other ways harm the longer-term stability and legitimacy of the government. A cycle of patronage and the unmasking of patronage (and exploitation) is thus set up that makes the political future uncertain.

(Strathem 1993, p. 57)

Not only has there been an escalation in violence, there has been a similar escalation in forms of activity which, by Western standards, must be deemed 'corruption'. Since politicians are as concerned with their standing and support in their home regions as they are with the management of government, administrative organisation is subverted to their requirements. As Strathern observes:

One can see a conflict of opinion developing here between the public service and the politicians. Senior public servants largely see their task as the expansion of the sphere of administration and of 'law and order'. They sometimes are of the opinion that politicians can get in the way of this process both by commoditizing, and so corrupting, politics and by attempting to usurp the spheres of administrative work in favour of their own patronage networks ..

(Strathern 1993, p. 46)

Papua New Guinea faces an uncertain future. Its parliamentarians, for many years to come, will remain caught between the demands of membership in a community of politicians and the demands of their electorates. Leadership will continue to reflect the consequences of those demands. And the national government will continue to be seen, by the vast majority of Papua New Guineans, as a source of wealth to be tapped by members of parliament for the benefit of their supporters, whether at the national or the local level.

End Notes

1 Papua New Guinea communities provide women with few opportunities in public life. Since 1975, there have been only three female members of parliament. Those women who have exercised political leadership have most usually done so through the Kafaina or Wok Meri Movement. As Warry (1987) has described for the 1980s: 'Today Kafaina, or Wok Meri as it is called in the Eastern Highlands Province, provides an institutional framework that links together thousands of women from different tribal and language areas ... Kafaina beliefs are concerned with the inherent power of females and their ability to produce wealth ... Kafaina groups parallel traditional beliefs about the power of women as producers of food, caretakers of pigs and sources of male wealth in general.' (Warry 1987, p. 147). See Sexton (1986) for an account of the movement.

2 A kina was roughly equivalent to an Australian dollar through the period.

3 There is a wide-ranging literature on the characteristics of big men and other leaders in Papua New Guinea communities. The following is a brief selection of texts dealing with the issues: Brown 1990, 1987; Jolly 1987; Lederman 1990; Lindstrom 1990, 1988; McDowell 1990; Podolefsky 1990; Strathern & Ongka 1979; Strathern 1985.

4 See A Reciprocity Continuum for more on this.

References

Axline, W.A. 1988. 'Policy implementation in Papua New Guinea: Decentralisation and redistribution', Journal of Commonwealth and Comparative Politics, vol. 26, no. 1, March, pp. 72-103.  

Barnett, T. 1979. 'Politics and planning rhetoric in Papua New Guinea', Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol. 27, no. 4, pp. 769-84.

Berndt, R.M. & Lawrence, P. (eds) 1971. Politics in New Guinea: Traditional and in the Context of Change, Some Anthropological Perspectives, University of Western Australia Press, Nedlands, W A.

Brison, K.J. 1992. Just Talk: Gossip, Meetings and Power in a Papua New Guinea Village, University of California Press, Berkeley, Calif.

Brown, P. 1963. 'From anarchy to satrapy', American Anthropologist, vol. 65, pp. 1-15.

Brown, P. 1987. 'New men and big men: Emerging social stratification in the Third World, a case study from the New Guinea Highlands', Ethnology, vol. 26, no. 2, April, pp. 87-106.

Brown, P. 1990. 'Big man past and present: Model, person, hero, legend', Ethnology, vol. 29, no. 4, pp. 97-115.

Brown, P., Brookfield, H. & Grau, R. 1990. 'Land tenure and transfer in Chimbu Papua New Guinea: 1958-1984. A study in continuity and change accommodation and opportunism, Human-Ecology, vol. 18, no. 1, March, pp.21-49.

Chowning, A. & Goodenough, W. 1971. 'Lakalai: Politics in New Guinea', in Politics in New Guinea: Traditional and in the Context of Change, Some Anthropological Perspectives, eds R. Berndt & P. Lawrence, University of Western Australia Press, Nedlands, W A, pp. 113-36.

Griffin, A. & King, P. 1985. Issues and Leaders in the 1982 Elections in Papua New Guinea: A Collection of Campaign Speeches, Dept of Political and Administrative Studies, University of Papua New Guinea, Port Moresby.

Hinchliffe, K. 1980. 'Conflicts between national aims in Papua New Guinea: The case of decentralization and equality', Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol. 28, no. 4, July, pp. 819-38.

Holloway, Sir B. 1990. 'Decentralised system is a disaster', New Times, 1 February, Port Moreseby.

Jolly, M. 1987. 'The chimera of equality in Melanesia', Mankind, vol. 17, pp. 168-83.

King, P. 1989. Pangu Returns to Power: The 1982 Elections in Papua New Guinea, Dept of Political and Social Change, Research School of Pacific Studies, Australian National University, Australian National University Press, Canberra.

Lederman, R. 1990. 'Big men, large and small? Towards a comparative perspective', Ethnology, vol. 29, no. 1, January, pp. 3-15.

Lindstrom, L. 1988. 'Big men and the conversational marketplace of Tanna (Vanuatu)', Ethnos, vol. 53, no. 3-4, pp. 159-89.

Lindstrom, L. 1990. Big men as ancestors: Inspiration and copyrights on Tanna (Vanuatu)', Ethnology, vol. 29, no. 4, October, pp. 313-26.

Loveday, P. 1975. Parties in Papua New Guinea, 1972-74, Institute of Development Studies, University of Sussex, Brighton, UK.

McDowell, N. 1990. 'Competitive equality in Melanesia: An exploratory essay', Journal of the Polynesian Society, vol. 99, no. 2, pp.179-204.

Maddick, H. 1968. Democracy, Decentralisation, and Development, Asia Publishing House, New Delhi.

Nyerere, J. 1968. Freedom and Development, Government of Tanzania, Dar-es-Salaam.

Oliver, D. 1955. A Solomon Islands Society, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Podolefsky, A. 1990. 'Mediator roles in Simbu conflict management', Ethnology, vol. 29, no. 1, January, pp. 67-81.

PPC 1990. Report on the Investigation into and on Matters Giving Rise to the Provisional Suspension of the Morobe Provincial Government, vol. 1, Permanent Parliamentary Committee (PPe) on Provincial Government Suspension, Port Moresby.

Premdas, R.R. & Steeves, JS. 1984. Decentralisation and Political Change in Melanesia: Papua New Guinea, The Solomon Islands, and Vanuatu, South Pacific Forum Working Paper, no. 3, Suva.

Read, K.E. 1959. 'Leadership and consensus in a New Guinea society', American Anthropologist, vol. 61, pp. 425-36.

Robison, R. 1990. Power and Economy in Suharto's Indonesia, The Journal of Contemporary Asia Publishers, Manila.

Sahlins, M.D. 1963. 'Poor man, rich man, big-man, chief: Political types in Melanesia and Polynesia', Comparative Studies in Society and History, vol. 5, pp. 283-303.

Salisbury, R.F. 1970. Vunamami: Economic Transformation in a Traditional Society, Melbourne University Press, Melbourne.  

Sexton, L.D. 1986. Mothers of Money, Daughters of Coffee: The Wok Meri Movement, UMI Research Press, Ann Arbor, Mich.

Strathern, A.J. 1985. 'Lineages and big-men: Comments on an ancient paradox', Mankind, vol 15, no. 2, August, pp. 101-9.

Strathern, A.J. 1993. 'Violence and political change in Papua New Guinea', Pacific Studies, vol. 16, no. 4, pp. 41-{j0.

Strathern, A.J. (trans) & Ongka 1979. Ongka: A Self-Account by a New Guinea Big-Man, Duckworth, Fort Worth, Tex.

Tordoff, W. 1987. 'Issues in decentralisation in Papua New Guinea', Journal of Commonwealth and Comparative Politics, vol. 25, no. 1, pp. 44- 70.

Ward, R.G. (ed.) 1970. An Atlas of Papua and New Guinea, Dept of Geography, University of Papua & New Guinea, Port Moresby.

Warry, W. 1987. Chuave Politics: Changing Patterns of Leadership in the New Guinea Highlands, Dept of Political and Social Change, Research School of Pacific Studies, Australian National University, Canberra.